Page 1 of 5
1
2
3
... LastLast
  1. #1
    The Unstoppable Force Theodarzna's Avatar
    7+ Year Old Account
    Join Date
    Sep 2015
    Location
    NorCal
    Posts
    24,166

    Lightbulb Neoliberalism: The Movement That Dare Not Speak Its Name

    Reactions against the use of the term neoliberalism have usually taken one of two forms: first, that “neoliberalism” is nothing more than a fevered delusion or a mirage perhaps shared with a few other addled persons, and thus best ignored; and second, that if such a thing does indeed exist, it is far too uneven and inconsistent to count as a serious analytical category. To be fair, mobilization of the term “neoliberalism” has grown uncomfortably sloppy among a subset of those on the left. Broadsides have equated it to laissez-faire economics, market fundamentalism, libertarianism, globalization, biopolitics, financialization, and many other things. Even some of the most celebrated recent intellectual histories on the topic, like Angus Burgin’s Great Persuasion or Daniel Stedman Jones’s Masters of the Universe, have tended either to abjure the label altogether, or to make a botch of distinguishing neoliberals from libertarians and plain vanilla conservatives. Although there has been an abundance of books and papers with the word “neoliberalism” in the title, perhaps the quality of thought about the subject has not exactly been flourishing.

    The elusiveness of neoliberalism, however, ultimately stems from denials that neoliberals themselves have made about their efforts. While we can fairly well identify the roster of who should be acknowledged as a part of the movement, at least from its beginnings in the 1930s until the recent past, we are confronted with the fact that, in public, they themselves roundly deny the existence of any such well-defined thought collective, and stridently resist the label of neoliberalism. Not only do they wash their hands of most of the documented activities of what I call the Neoliberal Thought Collective (as when Hayek and Friedman abjured the Pinochet interlude in Chile) but they complain that their opponents, the socialists, have always gotten the better of them. And thus, they claim, their political project has never enjoyed any real successes, ever, anywhere, contrary to all evidence brought to the table. They are forever the bridesmaid of conservative parties but never the bride. Given the sheer numbers of people involved, the astronomical sums of money, and their cultural dominance of the airwaves, this sad-sack victimhood is really quite remarkable, and itself calls for serious examination. Perhaps it has something to do with the fact that a political movement that dare not speak its own name has intellectual contradictions that it dare not air openly.

    The tendency to deny the existence of neoliberalism raises four questions that I will address here: Why do people think the “neoliberal” label is so very awful? Is it possible to pin down what neoliberalism signifies, and how you can tell a neoliberal when you encounter one? Do neoliberals often tell the truth about their doctrine? And, finally, can a working understanding of neoliberalism illuminate contemporary epistemic issues, such as the project to displace old-school science with “open science”?

    The Chicago School and Neoliberalism

    It is a remarkable and dumbfounding fact that everyone suddenly reverts to strict nominalism when encountering neoliberalism. They circle round the word as if it were a dead animal in the middle of the road, crushed and distended, trying to figure out what to call it even though, strictly speaking, they reserve judgment over whether it is even really there. Neoliberalism, they complain, is a rascal concept, a spitting pejorative, a bloated concept of dubious utility, polysemous yet empty at the core, a sloppy synonym for capitalism, a hymn to “free markets” (as though those words were any less slippery).

    Self-identified neoliberals are hard to come by. There is no political party or national regime that touts the “neoliberal” moniker. It does not denote a professional position in economics or anywhere else. And yet many take the view that neoliberalism’s continued reign is among the most perplexing puzzles of our time.1 In place of the supposedly slippery term neoliberalism, political observers and specialists alike tend to substitute incorrect synonyms like “liberals” or “libertarians” or (God forbid) “conservatives.”

    This queasiness around labels (as in so much else in the later authors) in fact merely channels Friedrich Hayek’s own brief skirmish with nominalism right after World War II:

    The difficulty which we encounter is not merely the familiar fact that the current political terms are notoriously ambiguous or even that the same term often means nearly the opposite to different groups. There is the much more serious fact that the same word frequently appears to unite people who in fact believe in contradictory and irreconcilable ideals. Terms like “liberalism” or “democracy,” “capitalism” or “socialism,” today no longer stand for coherent systems of ideas. They have come to describe aggregations of quite heterogeneous principles and facts which historical accident has associated with these words.

    Words that stand in for political doctrines have been notoriously polysemous and unreliable as freestanding categories. Anyone who has ever traveled outside the Anglosphere rapidly learns the disconcerting fact that the term “liberal,” which designates the soft Left in North America, designates its opposite in France or Latin America. By this standard, not only neoliberalism but “liberalism” also doesn’t really exist.

    Yet it is a mistake to believe that the only legitimate labels are those which are freely embraced by the very people who espouse the doctrines in question. How many people recall that the “Austrian School” moniker originated as a disparaging epithet coined by their opponents, the German Historical School? Or that the institutionalist Thorstein Veblen was the first person to coin the term “neoclassical” to refer to the sort of economics promulgated by Alfred Marshall and his students? Both of these names stuck over time, usually for good reasons. Political doctrines and economic theories can rarely be confined to neat, discrete boxes. But that does not belie the fact that powerful ideas that spark long-lived movements do eventually roll in well-worn grooves. One can use such labels as shorthand to indicate family resemblances in the manner of Wittgenstein, as long as one is suitably careful to acknowledge dependence on context, and to take note of how speakers themselves tend to negotiate the indeterminacies of their own doctrines.

    Even some more careful analyses of neoliberals make fundamental errors about the cast of neoliberal thought. Take David Harvey’s Brief History of Neoliberalism, currently the most cited work on the topic. After correctly noting that the figures in question often misleadingly called themselves “liberals,” he then writes: “The neoliberal label signaled their adherence to those free market principles of neoclassical economics. . . . Neoliberal doctrine was therefore deeply opposed to state interventionist theories.”

    Here, packed into two short sentences, we encounter two of the most frequent errors committed by outsiders who wade into neoliberal waters. First, and one which cannot be stressed enough: however much they sound alike, neoliberalism and neoclassical economics are two different schools of thought. The latter dates from the 1870s, and encompasses mathematical models of the constrained optimization of utility, which still exists today as the core of economic orthodoxy. Neoliberalism by contrast dates from the 1940s, if not a bit earlier, and is a general philosophy of market society, and not some narrow set of doctrines restricted to economics. Furthermore, neoliberals are skeptical of “scientism,” such as heavy dependence on mathematics, and have a conflicted relationship to neoclassical economics. Neoliberals should not be disparaged as “market fundamentalists,” for they believe that human beings must be transformed in order to establish their ideal society. If anything, it is rather the neoclassical economists who more properly warrant the moniker “market fundamentalist,” since they are incapable of theorizing anything outside their rather impoverished notion of “the market.” The neoliberals are Socratic polymaths by comparison.

    I think it is fairly easy to identify the source of this confusion. Most people likely get their impressions of neoliberal doctrine from some exposure to the American poster boy for the Mont Pèlerin Society, Milton Friedman. His 1980 pop book Free to Choose is still in print, and the PBS documentary series of the same name is now wildly popular on YouTube. Friedman was the most famous representative of the “Chicago School of Economics” in the period from roughly 1950 to 1990, and went out of his way to spread the good news of neoliberalism in the media and in political arenas. This created a number of distortions in public perception of the doctrine, which persist down to the present.

    The first distortion is the impression that neoliberal theory is identical to neoclassical economics. A judicious dose of real intellectual history can help clear up this confusion. The Chicago School was established in the immediate postwar era as a complement to the Mont Pèlerin Society, and was dedicated to the reconciliation of the nascent neoliberal ideas with a rather simplistic form of neoclassical economics. This reconciliation was never entirely successful, and was resisted at other major centers of postwar neoclassical theory, such as MIT and the Cowles Commission. Indeed, there is a murky catchphrase that obliquely refers to this unresolved tension, one that claims there is a “freshwater” versus a “saltwater” branch of neoclassical orthodoxy. This supposed reference to geography misses the historical dynamic, which was closer to diluted price theory, starting as backwater economics before eventually becoming economic Dasani. Interestingly, the Chicago drive to reconciliation was also resisted within the neoliberal thought collective as well, with Hayek, the Austrian School, and the Ordoliberals all rejecting the legitimacy of neoclassical economic theory as an appropriate framework within which to understand how the market worked. So the situation resembles a Venn diagram, in which there is some overlap between neoliberalism and neoclassical economics, but significant portions of the two remain fundamentally distinct, at least from the 1950s to 1990s. Yet because Milton Friedman had become the mouthpiece for the neoliberal program in this era in the public sphere, laypersons understandably tended to infer that orthodox neoclassical economics and something like neoliberal politics were really the same thing.

    The second distortion resulted from the fact that Friedman was a master simplifier, even if it meant misrepresenting what fellow neoliberals had actually written, and the policies they had actually promoted. Nowhere was this more evident than when he boiled down neoliberal politics to the desiccated slogan “market good, government bad.” He praised “deregulation” and “privatization.” But in practice the truth was hidden in the details, and that always involved government power. In other words, he falsely conflated neoliberalism with libertarianism, even though he was always careful to register some minor qualifications when pressed to clarify his position.

    While it is undeniable that neoliberals routinely disparage the state, both back then and now, it does not follow that they are politically libertarian or, as David Harvey would have it, that they are implacably opposed to state interventions in the economy and society. Harvey’s error is distressing, since even Antonio Gramsci understood this: “Moreover, laissez-faire liberalism, too, must be introduced by law, through the intervention of political power: it is an act of will, not the spontaneous, automatic expression of economic facts.” From the 1940s onward, the distinguishing characteristic of neoliberal doctrines and practice is that they embrace this prospect of repurposing the strong state to impose their vision of a society properly open to the dominance of the market as they conceive it. Neoliberals from Friedrich Hayek to James Buchanan to Richard Posner to Alexander Rüstow (who invented the term Vitalpolitik, which became Foucault’s “biopolitics”) to Jacques Rueff, not to mention a plethora of figures after 1970, all explicitly proposed policies to strengthen the state.

    Friedman’s own trademark proposals, like putting the money supply on autopilot, or replacing public schools with vouchers, required an extremely strong state to enforce them. While neoliberal think tanks rile up the base with debt clocks and boogeyman statistics of ratios of government expenditure to GDP, neoliberal politicians organize a host of new state activities to fortify their markets. They extravagantly increase incarceration and policing of those whom they deem unfit for the marketplace. They expand both state and corporate power to exercise surveillance and manipulation of subject populations while dismantling judicial recourse to resist such encroachments. Neoliberals introduce new property rights (like intellectual property) to cement into place their extensions of market valuations to situations where they were absent. They strengthen international sanctions such as the Trans-Pacific Partnership and investor-state dispute settlement schemes to circumvent and neutralize national social legislation they dislike. They bail out and subsidize private banking systems at the cost of many multiples of existing national income. And they define corporations as legal persons in order to facilitate the buying of elections.

    The blue-sky writings of neoliberals with regard to the state are, if anything, even more daunting. In the imaginary constitution proposed in Hayek’s Law, Legislation and Liberty, he suggests that politicians be rendered more powerful: in the imagined upper legislative house, Hayek stipulates, only men of substantial property over age forty-five would be eligible to vote or be elected; no political parties would be allowed; and each member would stand for a hefty fifteen-year term. This illustrates the larger neoliberal predisposition to be very leery of democracy, and thus to stymie public participation through the concentration of political power in fewer hands. James Buchanan proposed something very similar. This is just about as far from libertarianism as one could get, short of brute dictatorship.

    So here is the answer to my first question: people think the label “neoliberalism” is an awful neologism because the neoliberals have been so good at covering their tracks, obscuring what they stand for, and denying the level of coherence which they have achieved in their long march to legitimacy. Back when some of these proposals were just a gleam in Hayek’s eye, they did explicitly use the term “neoliberalism” to describe the project that, back then, did not yet exist—even Milton Friedman used it in print. But once their program looked like it would start to jell, and subsequently start reshaping both the state and the market more to their liking, they abruptly abjured any reference to that label, and sometime in the later 1950s, following the lead of Hayek, they began to call themselves “classical liberals.” This attempt at rebranding was an utter travesty because, as they moved from reconceptualization of one area of human experience to another, the resulting doctrines contradicted classical liberalism point by point, and term by term. It might be worthwhile for us who come after to insist upon the relevance of things that put the neo- in neoliberalism.

    What’s New about Neoliberalism?


    In a nutshell, classical liberalism imagined a night watchman state that would set the boundaries for the natural growth of the market, like a shepherd tending his flock. Markets were born, not made. The principles of good governance and liberty would be dictated by natural rights of individual humans, or perhaps by the prudent accretion of tradition. People needed to be nurtured first to find themselves, in order to act as legitimate citizens in liberal society. Society would be protected from the disruptive character of the market by something like John Stuart Mill’s “harm principle”: colloquially, the freedom of my fist stops at the freedom of your face. The neoliberals were having none of that, and explicitly said so.

    Far from trying to preserve society against the unintended consequences of the operations of markets, as democratic liberalism sought to do, neoliberal doctrine instead set out actively to dismantle those aspects of society which might resist the purportedly inexorable logic of “catallactics,” and to reshape it in the market’s image. For neoliberals, freedom and the market would be treated as identical. Their rallying cry was to remove the foundation of liberty from natural rights or tradition, and reposition it upon an entirely novel theory concerning what a market was, or should be. They could not acknowledge individual natural rights, because they sought to tutor the masses to become the agent the market would be most likely to deem successful. The market no longer gave you what you wanted; you had to capitulate to what the market wanted. All areas of life could be better configured to behave as if they were more market-like. Gary Becker, for example, a member of the Mont Pèlerin Society, proposed a market-based approach to allow for a socially optimal level of crime, and advocated a revolutionary extension of marginal calculus to include the “shadow costs” and benefits associated with “children, prestige or esteem, health, altruism, envy, and pleasure of the senses.” Becker even proposed an economic model of the “dating market,” one consequence of which was the proposition that polygamy for successful, wealthy men could be politically rationalized. And voilà! The Sunday New York Times produced an article saying just that, as if it were real news. Classical liberals like Mill or Michael Oakeshott would be spinning in their graves.

    The intellectual content of neoliberalism is something that warrants sustained discussion, but this can only happen once critical historians can admit they are no longer basing their evaluations on the isolated writings of a single author. There is no convenient crib sheet describing what the modern neoliberal thought collective (for brevity, NTC) actually believes. Nevertheless, neoliberalism does have certain themes that are regularly sounded in emanations from the NTC:
    1. “Free” markets do not occur naturally. They must be actively constructed through political organizing.
    2. “The market” is an information processor, and the most efficient one possible—more efficient than any government or any single human ever could be. Truth can only be validated by the market.
    3. Market society is, and therefore should be, the natural and inexorable state of humankind.
    4. The political goal of neoliberals is not to destroy the state, but to take control of it, and to redefine its structure and function, in order to create and maintain the market-friendly culture.
    5. There is no contradiction between public/politics/citizen and private/market/entrepreneur-consumer—because the latter does and should eclipse the former.
    6. The most important virtue—more important than justice, or anything else—is freedom, defined “negatively” as “freedom to choose,” and most importantly, defined as the freedom to acquiesce to the imperatives of the market.
    7. Capital has a natural right to flow freely across national boundaries.
    8. Inequality—of resources, income, wealth, and even political rights—is a good thing; it prompts productivity, because people envy the rich and emulate them; people who complain about inequality are either sore losers or old fogies, who need to get hip to the way things work nowadays.
    9. Corporations can do no wrong—by definition. Competition will take care of all problems, including any tendency to monopoly.
    10. The market, engineered and promoted by neoliberal experts, can always provide solutions to problems seemingly caused by the market in the first place: there’s always “an app for that.”
    11. There is no difference between is and should be: “free” markets both should be (normatively) and are (positively) the most efficient economic system, and the most just way of doing politics, and the most empirically true description of human behavior, and the most ethical and moral way to live—which in turn explains, and justifies, why their versions of “free” markets should be and, as neoliberals build more and more power, increasingly are universal.

    No wonder outsiders are dazed and confused. The neoliberal revolutionaries, contemptuous of tradition, conjured a fake tradition to mask their true intentions. They did this while explicitly abjuring the label of “conservative.” But there is one more reason that outsiders tend to think it a mistake to posit an effective intellectual formation called “neoliberalism.” Nowadays we doubt that ideas, and particularly political ideas, are the product of the concerted efforts of some thought collective stretching over generations, engaging in critique and reconstruction, fine-tuning and elaborating doctrine, while keeping focused upon problems of implementation and feasibility. Indeed, that doubt is evidence of neoliberal preconceptions having seeped into all of our thought processes. Yet that is an exact description of how neoliberalism developed, in the manner (as I insist on calling it) of a thought collective: sanctioned members are encouraged to innovate and embellish in small ways, but an excess of doctrinal heresy gets one expelled from participation. Central dogmas are not codified or dictated by any single prophet; no one delivers the Tablets down from the “Mont”; and you cannot adequately understand neoliberalism solely by reading Hayek or Milton Friedman, for that matter. While we can locate its origins in 1947, it has undergone much revision since then, and is still a hydra-headed Gorgon to this very day.

    Neoliberal Detection Devices


    My description of the neoliberal thought collective sometimes prompts worry that its doctrines might be too diverse to determine what ideas are and are not neoliberal. But here is where history can solve real epistemic problems. A little reading, along with some archival digging, reveals that the central node of initial neoliberal organization was the Mont Pèlerin Society, or MPS, first convened in Switzerland in 1947. As one might expect, it started out small—a mere thirty-nine participants—but it had participants from a diverse set of countries and not simply from the United States. It later grew so rapidly that its membership was capped at five hundred, where it remains today. For the first two decades, Hayek alone decided who could be invited to join the relatively closed discussion circle. After the 1960s, one would need to be approached by two members and asked to join, after undergoing some vetting procedure. No one could simply crash the party.

    The purpose of the MPS was to create a special space where people of like-minded political ideals could gather together to debate the outlines of a future movement diverging from classical liberalism, without having to suffer the indignities of ridicule for their often blue-sky proposals. They also sought to evade their fifth-column reputation as a society closely aligned with powerful but dubious postwar interests—including some of the rich individuals invited to attend. Even the name of the society itself was chosen to be relatively anodyne, signaling little in the way of substantive content to outsiders. Many members would indeed hold academic posts in a range of disciplines, but this was not a precondition of MPS membership. The MPS would thus also be expanded to encompass various powerful capitalists, and not just intellectuals.

    The story of the neoliberal thought collective from 1947 to the present is the saga of the “building out” of both knowledge production and political action capacities, with the MPS more or less at the center, until the turn of the millennium. Neoliberals like Hayek may have scorned the universities, but they certainly understood the need to have a foothold in at least a few of them. The joint membership in MPS and those departments is another way we can trace the neoliberals. One then might regard specific academic departments where the neoliberals came to dominate before 1980 (University of Chicago Economics, the LSE, l’Institut universitaire des hautes études internationales at Geneva, St Andrews in Scotland, Freiburg, the Virginia School, George Mason University) as the next outer layer of neoliberal infrastructure, an emergent public face of the thought collective—although one rarely publicly acknowledging its links to the MPS.

    The expansion of the think tank infrastructure accelerated in the 1970s, and spread to most corners of the world. Another shell of infrastructure was fashioned as the special-purpose foundations for the education and promotion of neoliberal doctrines: in its early days, these included entities such as the Volker Fund, the Earhart Foundation, the Relm Foundation, the Lilly Endowment, the John M. Olin Foundation, the Bradley Foundation, and the Foundation for Economic Education. The Coors and Koch family foundations were critical players in the United States. The Intercollegiate Society of Individualists (ISI, later the Intercollegiate Studies Institute) served as a recruitment center for bright young things to be scouted and groomed for the movement in the United States; other countries had similar “educational” foundations.

    Core MPS members helped shape the construction of the think-tank infrastructure. In Thatcher’s Britain, the founding of the Institute of Economic Affairs (IEA) can be traced back to advice delivered to Antony Fisher, a businessman who had read and had been impressed by the Reader’s Digest version of Hayek’s Road to Serfdom. Fisher went to see Hayek and asked for his advice as to what he should do to further the cause. Hayek advised him not to go into politics, but instead to start a public policy think tank. This he was able to do—with the support of his profitable firm, Buxted Chickens, the first of the British battery hen companies. The wellsprings of neoliberal liberty in Britain, friends of the IEA might be forced to admit, had a little too much for comfort to do with the imprisonment of hens. But it had almost nothing to do with the spontaneous inclinations of wealthy people each acting on their own.

    While most Americans were oblivious to the spreading tentacles of the collective, politically active intellectuals in other countries were far quicker to realize that something new and significant was happening. It was therefore authors on the periphery, primarily in Latin America and Francophone countries, who took to using the terminology of “neoliberalism” in languages other than English, earlier and with greater frequency. The Anglophone context has been laggard relative to the rest of the world in attempting to discern the shape and structure of this political formation.

    Neoliberalism and American Conservatism


    There is no good history of the expansion of the intellectual and political capacity of the neoliberal thought collective written by the neoliberals themselves, although there are revealing accounts here and there of specific intellectuals and particular think tanks.15 The individualist bias also infects these memoirs of the NTC, however, since to pull back and expose the density of interconnections would smack of, well, a self-exposed conspiracy. But the political rise of the New Right also required suppressing the sharp differences of various political factions that would normally have had nothing to do with one another: the cultural conservatives, Russell Kirk’s paleoconservatives, the warlike neocons, the evangelical Right, the libertarians, the white supremacists, and a whole host of others. Since much of the “fusionism” that elided these differences was promoted at the key think tanks starting in the 1970s, the think tankers themselves had to repress being very precise over how certain strains of their political movement—and in particular the neoliberals—had championed doctrines that clashed with the other factions. Worse, the tonier neoliberals, used to hobnobbing with the rich, also tended to find their political fellow travelers a bit shabby and thus insalubrious companions. Hence the very tactical successes of the New Right itself militated against insiders writing detailed outlines of the neoliberal thought collective.

    One of the best short definitions of neoliberalism is offered by Will Davies—namely, that it is a political doctrine depending upon a strong state to pursue the disenchantment of politics by means of economics. If that sounds like an oxymoron, well, maybe that’s the nub of the project. As Margaret Thatcher is reported to have said, “Economics is the method, but the object is to change the soul.” Behind closed doors, even a popularizing neoliberal like Milton Friedman could be known to wax far more reflective. In public, Friedman would plead that he wanted the same ultimate objectives as his opponents, only differing in the most efficacious means to achieve them. In private, he would concede his intolerance for democracy, admit that true libertarianism was a pipe dream, confess his disdain for many of the key doctrines of Austrian economics, his contempt for Keynes, and assert that postwar foreign policy had taken a wrong turn with the Marshall Plan.

    There was nothing simple about Friedman’s precarious balancing act at the heart of the neoliberal project, and it never consisted of simple-minded libertarianism. The counterevidence comes in Friedman’s own private correspondence, such as a 1973 letter to Pat Buchanan: “We are talking at cross-purposes because of what I regard as the important necessity of keeping clearly separate the long-run ideal goal and the tactical steps that may be appropriate in moving towards it.” This distinction did not merely consist of the trimming of the sails to render their political project more palatable to the masses. It consisted of living a sequence of double truths—one for the masses, another for battle-hardened insiders—that grew organically out of the key political and epistemological positions innovated by the thought collective over the last sixty years.

    The hallmark of the neoliberal thought collective was that they more or less accepted the inherited image of an addled and befuddled populace, but thoroughly rejected any appeals to a scientific technocracy to instill some discipline in the masses. For them, the discombobulation of the masses was not a reason for despair, but rather the necessary compost out of which a spontaneous order might blossom.18 The primary way this would come to pass was through acknowledgement that “the market” was an information processor more powerful and more efficacious than any human being was or could ever be. The cretinous and nescient would propose; the market would dispose. In effect, the NTC believed if only the masses could learn to subordinate their ambitions and desires to market dictates, then their deficient understandings and flawed syllogisms could be regarded as convenient expedients smoothing the path to order, rather than as political obstacles to be overcome, as in the technocratic orientation of postwar social sciences. And, conveniently, the neoliberals would mobilize numerous institutional structures to nudge the people down that path.

    Hence, when it came to the simple matter of bamboozling the masses with ripping tales of government as the very embodiment of evil, as Friedman did, there were never any qualms expressed about their simultaneous drive to take over the Republican Party, and then the U.S. government, in order to impose a strong state and an even stronger set of state-instituted novel markets. The neoliberals often had to disguise their true allegiances from the masses: as Friedman once claimed, “the two groups that threaten the free market the most are businessmen and intellectuals.” Yet Friedman promoted the destruction of state education and the privatization of universities to put the intellectuals out of business; he never attacked the businessmen to any equivalent degree. Indeed, he openly preached the doctrine that corporations had no responsibilities to society other than to maximize their profits; if corporations were persons, they were of the purest strain of self-interested creatures, free from all surly bonds of obligation. The demonization of the state relative to the corporation was the epitome of the short-term tactic; the usurpation of power to the extent of reregulation (not deregulation) and extension of state power both at home and abroad were the long-term goals. No matter what Grover Norquist might rabbit on about, no neoliberal in government has ever actually shrunk the size of the state, much less drowned it in a bathtub. That was merely red meat for the groundlings. While in power, neoliberals may have subcontracted out parts of government, but that rarely makes a dent in bureaucracy. The coercive power of government inexorably grows.

    The neoliberals believed that the market always knew better than any human being, but that humans would never voluntarily capitulate to that truth. People would resist utter abjection to the demands of the market; they would never completely dissolve into undifferentiated “human capital”; they would flinch at the idea that the political franchise needed to be restricted rather than broadened; they would be revolted that the condition of being “free to choose” only meant forgetting any political rights and giving up all pretense of being able to take charge of their own course through life. Neoliberal ideals would always be a hard sell, and the neoliberals realized that. How much easier to avoid all that with simplistic stories that fogged the mind of the masses: government is always bad; everything you need to know is already in Adam Smith; you can be anything you want to be; there is no such thing as class or the dead hand of history; everything can be made better if you just express yourself on some social media platform; there is nothing wrong with you that a little shopping won’t fix.

    In their heart of hearts, philosophically sophisticated neoliberals know that none of this is strictly true; and they can even concede this once in a while within internal discussions of neoliberal doctrine. After all, they can’t go around in public saying, “We must seize power and use all the tools of government to get the state to impose the ideal market on a recalcitrant populace.” Here they learned a lesson from the hard Marxist Left in the twentieth century, whose members repeatedly insisted that they might temporarily have to bring about turbocharged capitalism with enhanced exploitation as a necessary prelude to an eventual true socialism. Most political programs, at some juncture, must promise both A and not A simultaneously in order to exert sovereignty. What is noteworthy about the neoliberals is that they forged a unified doctrine and institutional structure attuned to do just that: they can reassure themselves that no human being is capable of second-guessing the “Truth of the Market,” and therefore spreading ignorance about their own true motives is not duplicity, but rather foaming the runway for the bearers of real civilization to land and take over.

    The net result of the reconciliation of theory and practice has been a political movement that dares not speak its own name.

    Neoliberal Knowledge Production


    While most people, members of the public and intellectuals alike, doubt whether neoliberalism even exists, its effects continue to show up in a wide variety of unexpected places. Since a central tenet of the doctrine is that markets validate truth, many of the stronger examples tend to involve epistemic phenomena, from the destruction of public schools to the denial of climate change (or the emphasis on market-oriented responses to it). I will close with a project that draws rather less commentary, but is equally important. Consider the recent push toward “open science.” Many people have the impression that “open science” is primarily about lay access to gated scientific papers published by large for-profit firms; but in fact, that is a sideshow in the greater project to “open up” science. The neoliberal attitude is to wrest the very conduct of science away from its putatively untrustworthy experts, and subject it to a bracing market discipline. This is proposed as a panacea for whatever ails science: lack of democracy, public distrust of science, a suspected slowdown in scientific productivity, the corruption of modern scientific journals, the crisis of replicability in scientific journals, and much else.

    The whole thing kicked off in the later 2000s, with rumors of something called “Science 2.0.” The New York Times then had the good sense to rebrand this imaginary utopia as “open science” in January 2012.20 The British Royal Society intervened close on its heels in 2012, with a public relations document entitled Science as an Open Enterprise. Subsequently, this was rapidly followed by a popularizing book, succeeded by a plethora of government white papers and policy documents. All sorts of obscure institutes and think tanks (the Ronin Institute, Center for Open Science, openscienceasap, UK Open Data Institute, pcori, Laura and John Arnold Foundation) then sprouted across the landscape, dedicated to propounding the virtues of “open science” for all and sundry.

    Thus it has come to pass that one consequence of the reverberating debates over the depth of these crises is to shift the terms of the remedies to different business models covering not only publication, but the peer review process as well. The entrepreneurial visions of a different configuration of science often evoke the magic of the marketplace to displace centuries-old practices of science: “You don’t have to reinvent the system, just nudge it a bit. . . . If you do it in an efficient way, people will do it. . . . Open science funders get a higher return on investment.” Since many scientists are attracted to the Open Science movement, believing it to be a renunciation of older commercial models, it is of paramount importance to understand precisely what the advocates of Open Science imagine will replace the current system of science organization.

    In the current climate, the favorite panacea for the replication crisis, and indeed everything else that ails science, is the watchword of more “transparency” imposed through the regimentation of social-media style internet platforms. Sometimes its advocates hint that such platforms will displace journals gradually, while others imagine a world without any old-fashioned journals at all. For instance, Mike Eisen, one of the pioneers of e-BioMed and PLOS has explicitly proposed that we should do away with journals and convert to a completely open system of preprints plus post-publication peer review. Others have yet even larger ambitions. Some early entrepreneurs openly advocated a “Facebook for Science,” as developments in social media began to shape expectations well afield. The current Open Science movement is trending toward an entirely public reengineering of science, from the earliest inchoate preparatory stages of a research project to the final dissemination and evaluation of the results. They imagine every aspect of scientific projects happening online, from the earliest preliminary literature review, to open data sets produced either by the researchers themselves or else by some other scientist, to real-time commentary by others on the research protocols, to drafts of reports uploaded to preprint servers, to quasi-journal publications online, to extensive peer review continuing well after the final draft is posted online.

    The most important aspect of this brave new world is the reason why its champions would believe that such a sloppy, unintegrated, bottom-up system, beset by waves of ignorant kibitzers would produce anything but white noise. The paladins of Science 2.0 love to quote the injunction, “With enough eyeballs, all bugs are shallow,” but that presumes that all science is merely an instrumental task, similar to the building of software. Here one has to show the dominant narrative of a political ontology that renders this revolutionary project plausible. And that is where a comprehension of the philosophical aspect of neoliberalism is indispensable.

    The crises of modern science, curiously enough, were largely brought about by neoliberal initiatives in the first place. First off, it was the neoliberal think tanks that first stoked the fires of science distrust amongst the populace that have led to the current predicament. It was neoliberals who provided the justification for the strengthening of intellectual property; it was the neoliberals who drove a wedge between state funding of research and state provision of university findings for the public good; it was neoliberal administrators who began to fragment the university into “cash cows” and loss-leader disciplines; it was neoliberal corporate officers who sought to wrest clinical trials away from academic health centers and toward contract research organizations to better control the disclosure or nondisclosure of the data generated. In some universities, students now have to sign nondisclosure agreements if they want initiation into the mysteries of faculty startups. It is no longer a matter of what you know; rather, success these days is your ability to position yourself with regard to the gatekeepers of what is known. Knowledge is everywhere hedged round with walls, legal prohibitions, and high market barriers breached only by those blessed with the riches required to be enrolled into the elect circles of modern science. Further, belief in the market as ultimate arbiter of truth has served to loosen the fetters of more conscious vetting of knowledge through the promulgation of negative results and the need to reprise research protocols. No wonder replication turns out to be so daunting. One can understand the desire to cast off these fetters and let the market do the work for us.

    The irony of the situation is that although this petrification of the scientific enterprise could largely be attributed to previous neoliberal “reforms” in the first instance, the remedy proposed nowadays is to double down on neoliberal policies, under the rubric of “open science.” Rather than simply foster “participation,” modern science is chockablock with proprietary websites that aim to reengineer the research process from the ground up. Internet startups are thick on the web, befitting the early stages of a push to engross and capture new electronic real estate. Academia.edu, Mendeley, and ResearchGate seek to foster artificial research communities to attract far-flung kibitzers to discuss and criticize the early-stage search for topics in which to become engaged in research. CERN has built Zendor in order to standardize the sharing of early-state research products. Open Notebook and Open Collaborate (and Microsoft’s failed myExperiment.org) are platforms to organize the early stages of research out in the open, even to the extent of conducting “virtual experiments,” while sites like Kickstarter offer alternative modes of seeking out research support. There are purported “citizen science” sites that entice nonscientists to perform remote labor for aspects of data processing which can be Taylorized and automated—SETI@home and Foldit are oft-cited examples.

    There is a plethora of platforms for publication management and controlled revision by multiple “authors,” although most of them are proprietary and closely held, in contrast with something like the physics prepublication site arXiv.org. Indeed, in clinical trials, most contract research organizations are built around such proprietary platforms. A burgeoning array of startups fosters post-publication platforms to evaluate and otherwise rank papers in various fields using what are dubbed AltMetrics, sometimes combined with collated unpaid reviews, as on the site Faculty of 1000. Firms like Science Exchange, Transcriptic, and Emerald Cloud Lab attempt to automate actual (mainly biochemical or clinical) lab procedures online, to better outsource and fragment the research process, and nominally, to render replication relatively effortless.

    While different platforms aim to apply the concepts of social media to some restricted subset of the research process, it does not take much imagination to anticipate that once the market shakes itself out, and one platform eventually comes to dominate its competitors within key segments of the research process at work in certain sciences, Google or some similar corporate entity will come along with its deep pockets, and integrate each segment into one grand proprietary Science 2.0 platform. Who would not then want to own the obligatory online passage point for the bulk of modern scientific research?

    Readers of Michel Foucault will know that the key to the process of spreading neoliberalism into everyday life involves recasting the individual into an entrepreneur of the self. Technologies such as Facebook already foster neoliberal notions of what it means to be human among teenagers who have never read a page of Hayek or political theory in their lives. Novel open science platforms inject neoliberal images of the marketplace of ideas into the scientific community. All the programs are besotted with the notion of complete identification of the individual as the locus of knowledge production, to the extent of imposing a unique online identifier for each participant, which links records across the platform and modular projects. The communal character of scientific research is summarily banished. Scientists are introduced to a quasi-market that constantly monitors their “net worth” through a range of metrics, scores, and indicators: h-index, Impact Factors, peer contacts, network affiliations, and the like. Regular email notifications keep nagging you to internalize these validations, and learn how to game them to your advantage. No direct managerial presence is required, because one automatically learns to internalize these seemingly objective market-like valuations, and they replace tenacious belief in a set of ideas or a particular research program. All it takes is a little nudge from your friendly online robot.

    What exactly is neoliberal about the incipient electronic manifestation of Science 2.0? First, the proliferation of open research platforms is primarily subordinate to the project of breaking up the research process into relatively separable component segments, in pursuit of their rationalization, which means, first and foremost, cost cutting. This happens through the intermediary of deskilling some of the tasks performed (“citizen science”) and automating others (AltMetrics, rendering big data accessible to web crawlers). Capturing freely donated labor which can later be turned into proprietary knowledge products is simply the analogue to capturing freely provided personal data. Thus Science 2.0 constitutes the removal of autonomy from the research scientist. Neoliberal science disparages scientists who remain in the rut of their own chosen disciplinary specialty or intellectual inspiration. What is required these days are flexible workers who can drop a research project at a moment’s notice, and turn on an interdisciplinary dime, in response to signals from “the market.” The short-term nature of science funding, as embodied in Kickstarter or recent innovations by the NIH, simply expresses this imperative.

    Second, the selling point of many of these platforms is not just that they provide direct services to the scientist involved. At every stage of research, they provide external third parties with the capacities for evaluation, validation, branding, and monitoring of research programs. Their nominal “openness” constitutes the ideal setup for near real-time surveillance of the research process—a Panopticon of Science, something which can be turned around and sold in just the same way that Facebook provides real-time surveillance of consumer behavior.

    Third, the paladins of Science 2.0 have moved far beyond quotidian concerns of appropriation of individual bits of intellectual property, like patents. What they have learned (similar to Microsoft, Google, and Uber) is that the company that controls the platform is the company that eventually comes to dominate the industry. Microsoft has learned to live with Open Source; Amazon leases out cloud computing; Google “gives away” Google Scholar. The future king of Science 2.0 will not be a mere patent troll, living as a parasite off companies who actually work the patents; it will not be perturbed by a few mandatory Open Data archives here and there. Instead, it will be the obligatory passage point for any commercial entity that wants to know where the research front of any particular science is right now, and who must be paid to influence and control that front.

    This race to be the King of Platforms that controls the future of Open Science is already happening. Far from being a relic of early stages of modern politics or economic liberalization, neoliberalism now appears in all the most “up-to-date” efforts of contemporary society. Neoliberalism is a conquering doctrine: it does not simply believe that “the market” will prevail, but instead that “the market” must be made to prevail. After having reshaped the global economy during the last forty years, neoliberalism has now begun to congeal into the very architecture of platforms like Facebook, ResearchGate, and Mendeley.

    Since Donald Trump came into office, many political scientists have taken to arguing over something they call “populism,” a label desperately in search of a referent if ever there was one. All the while, those same political scientists studiously ignore neoliberalism as an ignis fatuus, even though its history has been meticulously documented. All the while, the entire infrastructure of knowledge production itself is being comprehensively transformed in a neoliberal manner. I cannot think of a better instance of a weapon of mass distraction, which stymies comprehension of our current predicament.


    (source)

    Since the topic of Neo-Liberalism doesn't really get any direct coverage or mention, here is an entire article going over the movements history, aspirations, political nature and how it has shaped our world. Follow the link for a lot of citations for individual quotes, and comment, Why is Neo-Liberalism both ever present ideologically yet almost unmentioned?
    Quote Originally Posted by Crissi View Post
    i think I have my posse filled out now. Mars is Theo, Jupiter is Vanyali, Linadra is Venus, and Heather is Mercury. Dragon can be Pluto.
    On MMO-C we learn that Anti-Fascism is locking arms with corporations, the State Department and agreeing with the CIA, But opposing the CIA and corporate America, and thinking Jews have a right to buy land and can expect tenants to pay rent THAT is ultra-Fash Nazism. Bellingcat is an MI6/CIA cut out. Clyburn Truther.

  2. #2
    I Don't Work Here Endus's Avatar
    10+ Year Old Account
    Join Date
    Feb 2010
    Location
    Ottawa, ON
    Posts
    79,160
    Ahh, yes, the term that first emerged as and has basically always been nothing more than an empty pejorative.

    The silliest damned thing about it is that the specter of Neoliberalism always seems directed at left-wingers, when the supposed hallmarks; of deregulation, limitless growth, laissez-faire, self-correction of the markets, those are all hallmarks if classically liberal right-wing views.

    Mirowski's "Science 2.0" nonsense here is basically just a straight-up conspiracy theory, and seems to derive mostly from his distaste for how academia has integrated modern technological innovations into academic discourse and research, rather than any actual verifiable issue he can specifically identify.

    Ending off by criticizing people taking issue with "populism", because they're not paying attention to your own personal Great Satan, is ridiculous. He pretends that "populism" doesn't have at least as strong an academic history as neoliberalism, that there is similar confusion about the actual meaning of neoliberalism, etc. They're fairly comparable, in fact. Which he won't admit, because he wants everyone to ignore everything else and focus exclusively on his own personal boogeyman.
    Last edited by Endus; 2020-11-27 at 07:43 PM.


  3. #3
    The Unstoppable Force Theodarzna's Avatar
    7+ Year Old Account
    Join Date
    Sep 2015
    Location
    NorCal
    Posts
    24,166
    You got me, I didn't expect you to cite the Koch Brothers funded American Institute for Economic Research, as I am sure Free Market Think Tanks can comment on this matter in a non-biased way. This along with its sister NGO's such as the Atlas Network, Ayn Rand Institute, Cato Institute, the State Policy Network, the Charles Koch Institute are probably not reliable sources, come on you can do better than this.
    Quote Originally Posted by Crissi View Post
    i think I have my posse filled out now. Mars is Theo, Jupiter is Vanyali, Linadra is Venus, and Heather is Mercury. Dragon can be Pluto.
    On MMO-C we learn that Anti-Fascism is locking arms with corporations, the State Department and agreeing with the CIA, But opposing the CIA and corporate America, and thinking Jews have a right to buy land and can expect tenants to pay rent THAT is ultra-Fash Nazism. Bellingcat is an MI6/CIA cut out. Clyburn Truther.

  4. #4
    I Don't Work Here Endus's Avatar
    10+ Year Old Account
    Join Date
    Feb 2010
    Location
    Ottawa, ON
    Posts
    79,160
    Quote Originally Posted by Theodarzna View Post
    You got me, I didn't expect you to cite the Koch Brothers funded American Institute for Economic Research, as I am sure Free Market Think Tanks can comment on this matter in a non-biased way. This along with its sister NGO's such as the Atlas Network, Ayn Rand Institute, Cato Institute, the State Policy Network, the Charles Koch Institute are probably not reliable sources, come on you can do better than this.
    While I don't cherry-pick exclusively from sources I feel ideologically align with my views, as you apparently do, here you go, then.

    https://link.springer.com/article/10...116-009-9040-5
    https://www.theatlantic.com/business...eaning/528276/
    https://www.vox.com/polyarchy/2019/6...-neoliberalism
    https://nymag.com/intelligencer/2017...te-insult.html

    I'll acknowledge I have no clue whether Boas, author of the first, has any political leanings whatsoever, but the other three are all left-leaning sources, so you don't have to feign some phobia of ideological dirtiness for daring to dabble in their depths.

    I don't see a hell of a lot of value in the term when it gets applied to figures as wide-ranging as Barack Obama and Ronald Reagan. Particularly when most of the supposed tenets are just regular old classical liberalism. Laissez-faire capitalism. If you want to attack capitalist theory, by all means; I'm a socialist and I have little good to say about it. The use of "neoliberal" as a pejorative, though, suggests it's different from the good capitalism, and it's the combination of that and the wildly inconsistent use of the term recently that I take issue with.

    I'll notice you skipped right over my criticisms of some of the more nonsensical tangents your chosen source elected to diverge off onto.
    Last edited by Endus; 2020-11-27 at 08:04 PM.


  5. #5
    Banned JohnBrown1917's Avatar
    10+ Year Old Account
    Join Date
    Dec 2011
    Location
    Обединени социалистически щати на Америка
    Posts
    28,394
    Quote Originally Posted by Endus View Post
    Ahh, yes, the term that first emerged as and has basically always been nothing more than an empty pejorative.

    The silliest damned thing about it is that the specter of Neoliberalism always seems directed at left-wingers, when the supposed hallmarks; of deregulation, limitless growth, laissez-faire, self-correction of the markets, those are all hallmarks if classically liberal right-wing views.

    Mirowski's "Science 2.0" nonsense here is basically just a straight-up conspiracy theory, and seems to derive mostly from his distaste for how academia has integrated modern technological innovations into academic discourse and research, rather than any actual verifiable issue he can specifically identify.

    Ending off by criticizing people taking issue with "populism", because they're not paying attention to your own personal Great Satan, is ridiculous. He pretends that "populism" doesn't have at least as strong an academic history as neoliberalism, that there is similar confusion about the actual meaning of neoliberalism, etc. They're fairly comparable, in fact. Which he won't admit, because he wants everyone to ignore everything else and focus exclusively on his own personal boogeyman.
    Ah, yes, the idealogy that was birthed by the likes of Reagan and Thatcher is directed at left-wingers.
    I honestly have never seen it used to attack anybody left of center, only those who support the (classic) liberal economic system. Plenty of whom consider themselves to be neo liberals.

  6. #6
    Pandaren Monk wunksta's Avatar
    10+ Year Old Account
    Join Date
    Mar 2012
    Location
    Austin, TX
    Posts
    1,953
    Quote Originally Posted by Theodarzna View Post

    Since the topic of Neo-Liberalism doesn't really get any direct coverage or mention, here is an entire article going over the movements history, aspirations, political nature and how it has shaped our world. Follow the link for a lot of citations for individual quotes, and comment, Why is Neo-Liberalism both ever present ideologically yet almost unmentioned?
    Probably because it's become the defacto modus operandi of the American government for several decades regardless of political party. It's essentially become entrenched in how people view America because it's all people have known.

  7. #7
    I Don't Work Here Endus's Avatar
    10+ Year Old Account
    Join Date
    Feb 2010
    Location
    Ottawa, ON
    Posts
    79,160
    Quote Originally Posted by JohnBrown1917 View Post
    Ah, yes, the idealogy that was birthed by the likes of Reagan and Thatcher is directed at left-wingers.
    I honestly have never seen it used to attack anybody left of center, only those who support the (classic) liberal economic system. Plenty of whom consider themselves to be neo liberals.
    1> Not "birthed" by them at all; academic discussions of it date back to the first half of the 20th Century.
    2> The entire point is that people like Obama and the Clintons get called "neoliberals" pretty regularly, to the point that essentially everyone's a neolib. It's beyond silly these days.


  8. #8
    The Unstoppable Force PC2's Avatar
    7+ Year Old Account
    Join Date
    Feb 2015
    Location
    California
    Posts
    21,877
    Quote Originally Posted by Theodarzna View Post
    Self-identified neoliberals are hard to come by.
    I think it's extremely difficult to be a self-identified neoliberal because it's just about pragmatism in a mixed-economy rather than principles. Usually neoliberals will get pulled towards the left or towards libertarianism. When I think "neoliberal" I think of a person like Steven Pinker who supports a strong state government and a fair amount of taxes and regulations as long as they still fit within an optimistic vision for capitalism in the long run.
    Last edited by PC2; 2020-11-27 at 08:53 PM.

  9. #9
    I'm unsure why we need a book chapter as the impetus for conversation.

    That said I find it an effective shorthand when discussing modern-day robber baron's and their politico-economic beliefs then the more technically defined but highly confusing term Liberal conservatism
    Tonight for me is a special day. I want to go outside of the house of the girl I like with a gasoline barrel and write her name on the road and set it on fire and tell her to get out too see it (is this illegal)?

  10. #10
    I'll never understand why it isn't just called laissez faire capitalistic liberalism, that has the exact name of what is trying to be described. As for why it isn't talked about? I'd point towards the notion, that it isn't a key issue for political parties to either adhere to or to refuse, it is a default that they won't try and hold strong control over the economic market. With that said, it is also because no one lives in a purely neo-liberalistic country; you have welfare, you have regulations, you have a constant ongoing back and forth between government and the corporate world, on what they're allowed to do. Which, the pointing towards something like classic liberalism, is laughable. It was mainly a political philosophy, not a strongly followed tenant; you could get away with faaar more back then.

    Which ultimately, what I will say, do not confuse the notion of neo-liberalism or laissez faire capitalistic liberalism, with liberalism lead by corrupt politicians. Which kind of goes for all ideologies.
    Formerly Howeller, lost my account.

  11. #11
    The Unstoppable Force Theodarzna's Avatar
    7+ Year Old Account
    Join Date
    Sep 2015
    Location
    NorCal
    Posts
    24,166
    Quote Originally Posted by PC2 View Post
    I think it's extremely difficult to be a self-identified neoliberal because it's just about pragmatism in a mixed-economy rather than principles. Usually neoliberals will get pulled towards the left or towards libertarianism. When I think "neoliberal" I think of a person like Steven Pinker who supports a strong state government and a fair amount of taxes and regulations as long as they still fit within an optimistic vision for capitalism in the long run.
    The article describes what a Neo-Liberal is. What you've offered is the sales slogan to the masses, not the actual ideology as formulated and acted upon.

    - - - Updated - - -

    Quote Originally Posted by Howel View Post
    I'll never understand why it isn't just called laissez faire capitalistic liberalism, that has the exact name of what is trying to be described. As for why it isn't talked about? I'd point towards the notion, that it isn't a key issue for political parties to either adhere to or to refuse, it is a default that they won't try and hold strong control over the economic market. With that said, it is also because no one lives in a purely neo-liberalistic country; you have welfare, you have regulations, you have a constant ongoing back and forth between government and the corporate world, on what they're allowed to do. Which, the pointing towards something like classic liberalism, is laughable. It was mainly a political philosophy, not a strongly followed tenant; you could get away with faaar more back then.

    Which ultimately, what I will say, do not confuse the notion of neo-liberalism or laissez faire capitalistic liberalism, with liberalism lead by corrupt politicians. Which kind of goes for all ideologies.
    It isn't called that because there is a key distinction, Neo-Liberalism isn't really for "Small Government". The Market is not viewed as best for serving people but instead the project is to use the state to mold people to best serve the market. The market isn't a tool, but an end unto itself.
    Quote Originally Posted by Crissi View Post
    i think I have my posse filled out now. Mars is Theo, Jupiter is Vanyali, Linadra is Venus, and Heather is Mercury. Dragon can be Pluto.
    On MMO-C we learn that Anti-Fascism is locking arms with corporations, the State Department and agreeing with the CIA, But opposing the CIA and corporate America, and thinking Jews have a right to buy land and can expect tenants to pay rent THAT is ultra-Fash Nazism. Bellingcat is an MI6/CIA cut out. Clyburn Truther.

  12. #12
    Pandaren Monk wunksta's Avatar
    10+ Year Old Account
    Join Date
    Mar 2012
    Location
    Austin, TX
    Posts
    1,953
    Neo-liberalism also favors strong military intervention to ensure favorable market conditions in other countries. Making the world safe for American corporations.

  13. #13
    I Don't Work Here Endus's Avatar
    10+ Year Old Account
    Join Date
    Feb 2010
    Location
    Ottawa, ON
    Posts
    79,160
    Quote Originally Posted by Theodarzna View Post
    It isn't called that because there is a key distinction, Neo-Liberalism isn't really for "Small Government". The Market is not viewed as best for serving people but instead the project is to use the state to mold people to best serve the market. The market isn't a tool, but an end unto itself.
    But it did mean exactly that just a few decades ago, when the label was applied to Reagan and Thatcher with regularity.

    If the label's shifted in meaning that much and that quickly, then either the modern use of it in the way you describe is an error, or its meaning is so fluid that it's functionally meaningless and you'd be better served to find a specific term that clearly defines what you're talking about.

    "Neoliberalism" isn't a term that sprang out of nowhere in the 2010s. If your use of it clashes with its use in the '70s and '80s, something else is going on.


  14. #14
    Quote Originally Posted by Theodarzna View Post
    It isn't called that because there is a key distinction, Neo-Liberalism isn't really for "Small Government". The Market is not viewed as best for serving people but instead the project is to use the state to mold people to best serve the market. The market isn't a tool, but an end unto itself.
    Capitalistic liberalism doesn't note on the size on the government either, it is not a full ideology to which one adheres, it is principle adopted into full forms of governance. How do you mold the citizenry to serve the market? And how do you make it purely a one way win, where your participation is unequivocally somehow a loss?

    And lastly, again, I will pose it as a question this time, what's the distinction between neo-liberalism and liberalism lead by corrupt politicians?
    Formerly Howeller, lost my account.

  15. #15
    Banned JohnBrown1917's Avatar
    10+ Year Old Account
    Join Date
    Dec 2011
    Location
    Обединени социалистически щати на Америка
    Posts
    28,394
    Quote Originally Posted by Saltysquidoon View Post
    I'm unsure why we need a book chapter as the impetus for conversation.

    That said I find it an effective shorthand when discussing modern-day robber baron's and their politico-economic beliefs then the more technically defined but highly confusing term Liberal conservatism
    I've always seen neoliberalism and liberal convervatism as interchange-able terms.

  16. #16
    The Unstoppable Force Theodarzna's Avatar
    7+ Year Old Account
    Join Date
    Sep 2015
    Location
    NorCal
    Posts
    24,166
    Quote Originally Posted by Howel View Post
    Capitalistic liberalism doesn't note on the size on the government either, it is not a full ideology to which one adheres, it is principle adopted into full forms of governance. How do you mold the citizenry to serve the market? And how do you make it purely a one way win, where your participation is unequivocally somehow a loss?

    And lastly, again, I will pose it as a question this time, what's the distinction between neo-liberalism and liberalism lead by corrupt politicians?
    Quoting from the Article:
    While it is undeniable that neoliberals routinely disparage the state, both back then and now, it does not follow that they are politically libertarian or, as David Harvey would have it, that they are implacably opposed to state interventions in the economy and society. Harvey’s error is distressing, since even Antonio Gramsci understood this: “Moreover, laissez-faire liberalism, too, must be introduced by law, through the intervention of political power: it is an act of will, not the spontaneous, automatic expression of economic facts.” From the 1940s onward, the distinguishing characteristic of neoliberal doctrines and practice is that they embrace this prospect of repurposing the strong state to impose their vision of a society properly open to the dominance of the market as they conceive it. Neoliberals from Friedrich Hayek to James Buchanan to Richard Posner to Alexander Rüstow (who invented the term Vitalpolitik, which became Foucault’s “biopolitics”) to Jacques Rueff, not to mention a plethora of figures after 1970, all explicitly proposed policies to strengthen the state.

    Friedman’s own trademark proposals, like putting the money supply on autopilot, or replacing public schools with vouchers, required an extremely strong state to enforce them. While neoliberal think tanks rile up the base with debt clocks and boogeyman statistics of ratios of government expenditure to GDP, neoliberal politicians organize a host of new state activities to fortify their markets. They extravagantly increase incarceration and policing of those whom they deem unfit for the marketplace. They expand both state and corporate power to exercise surveillance and manipulation of subject populations while dismantling judicial recourse to resist such encroachments. Neoliberals introduce new property rights (like intellectual property) to cement into place their extensions of market valuations to situations where they were absent. They strengthen international sanctions such as the Trans-Pacific Partnership and investor-state dispute settlement schemes to circumvent and neutralize national social legislation they dislike. They bail out and subsidize private banking systems at the cost of many multiples of existing national income. And they define corporations as legal persons in order to facilitate the buying of elections.

    The blue-sky writings of neoliberals with regard to the state are, if anything, even more daunting. In the imaginary constitution proposed in Hayek’s Law, Legislation and Liberty, he suggests that politicians be rendered more powerful: in the imagined upper legislative house, Hayek stipulates, only men of substantial property over age forty-five would be eligible to vote or be elected; no political parties would be allowed; and each member would stand for a hefty fifteen-year term. This illustrates the larger neoliberal predisposition to be very leery of democracy, and thus to stymie public participation through the concentration of political power in fewer hands. James Buchanan proposed something very similar. This is just about as far from libertarianism as one could get, short of brute dictatorship.

    So here is the answer to my first question: people think the label “neoliberalism” is an awful neologism because the neoliberals have been so good at covering their tracks, obscuring what they stand for, and denying the level of coherence which they have achieved in their long march to legitimacy. Back when some of these proposals were just a gleam in Hayek’s eye, they did explicitly use the term “neoliberalism” to describe the project that, back then, did not yet exist—even Milton Friedman used it in print. But once their program looked like it would start to jell, and subsequently start reshaping both the state and the market more to their liking, they abruptly abjured any reference to that label, and sometime in the later 1950s, following the lead of Hayek, they began to call themselves “classical liberals.” This attempt at rebranding was an utter travesty because, as they moved from reconceptualization of one area of human experience to another, the resulting doctrines contradicted classical liberalism point by point, and term by term. It might be worthwhile for us who come after to insist upon the relevance of things that put the neo- in neoliberalism.
    The differences are mainly what the market is, is it a means or an ends. I am unsure why you mention "Corrupt Politicians". What would that have to do with anything?
    Quote Originally Posted by Crissi View Post
    i think I have my posse filled out now. Mars is Theo, Jupiter is Vanyali, Linadra is Venus, and Heather is Mercury. Dragon can be Pluto.
    On MMO-C we learn that Anti-Fascism is locking arms with corporations, the State Department and agreeing with the CIA, But opposing the CIA and corporate America, and thinking Jews have a right to buy land and can expect tenants to pay rent THAT is ultra-Fash Nazism. Bellingcat is an MI6/CIA cut out. Clyburn Truther.

  17. #17
    Quote Originally Posted by Theodarzna View Post
    Quoting from the Article: - snip
    I'll comment on the rest later, because it will take some time, but I have to address first. Friedrich Hayek - Classical liberal through and through, he literally fought the idea of neoliberalism. James Buchana - I... no, just no, not a neoliberalist. Richard Posner - Liberal/libertarian, some social conservative; not neoliberalist. Alexander Rüstow, pretty much coined the term, but he is more an ordoliberalist than neoliberalist, albeit the difference is limited. Jacques Rueff - libertarian conservative.

    Seriously, I don't know what the heck this author is on about, these people represent such a wide philosophical opinion on economics, that I can only come to the conclusion that if a person has even the slightest adherence to market economics being a reality, your a neoliberal. Like seriously, how an economist has written this, is beyond me. But I am starting to get a sense that it is an attempt to link everything together, and get it all tied back to Mont Pelerin Society, which leads to some backwards reasoning.
    Last edited by Howel; 2020-11-27 at 10:36 PM.
    Formerly Howeller, lost my account.

  18. #18
    The Unstoppable Force Theodarzna's Avatar
    7+ Year Old Account
    Join Date
    Sep 2015
    Location
    NorCal
    Posts
    24,166
    Quote Originally Posted by wunksta View Post
    Probably because it's become the defacto modus operandi of the American government for several decades regardless of political party. It's essentially become entrenched in how people view America because it's all people have known.
    Neoliberalism sets itself apart in a sense because it aims to reeducate the masses—housebreak them so to speak, into accepting the penetration of the market into every aspect of their lives. "The market" doesn't give you what you wanted; you have to capitulate to what "the market" wants. When viewed through this lens, all those examples of neoliberalism bringing down living standards, the expansion of the incarceration state, life becoming more precarious, gutting of labor, and the brutal invasions of other countries, they are a feature, not a bug, of neoliberalism. The warfare and I'd add incarceration aspects of the Neo-Liberal state are indeed core facets and important parts of it.

    - - - Updated - - -

    Quote Originally Posted by Howel View Post
    I'll comment on the rest later, because it will take some time, but I have to address first. Friedrich Hayek - Classical liberal through and through. James Buchana - I... no, just no, not a neoliberalist. Richard Posner - Liberal/libertarian, some social conservative; not neoliberalist. Alexander Rüstow, pretty much coined the term, but he is more a ordoliberalist than neoliberalist, albeit the difference is limited. Jacques Rueff - libertarian conservative.

    Seriously, I don't know what the heck this author is on about, these people represent such a wide philosophical opinion on economics, that I can only come to the conclusion that if a person has even the slightest adherence to market economics being a reality, your a neoliberal. Like seriously, how an economist has written this, is beyond me. But I am starting to get a sense that it is an attempt to link everything together, and get it all tied back to Mont Pelerin Society, which leads to some backwards reasoning.
    I have a feeling you simply aren't going to read the article.

    So, I'll quote your nomenclature confusion by again citing the article:

    This queasiness around labels (as in so much else in the later authors) in fact merely channels Friedrich Hayek’s own brief skirmish with nominalism right after World War II:

    The difficulty which we encounter is not merely the familiar fact that the current political terms are notoriously ambiguous or even that the same term often means nearly the opposite to different groups. There is the much more serious fact that the same word frequently appears to unite people who in fact believe in contradictory and irreconcilable ideals. Terms like “liberalism” or “democracy,” “capitalism” or “socialism,” today no longer stand for coherent systems of ideas. They have come to describe aggregations of quite heterogeneous principles and facts which historical accident has associated with these words.

    Words that stand in for political doctrines have been notoriously polysemous and unreliable as freestanding categories. Anyone who has ever traveled outside the Anglosphere rapidly learns the disconcerting fact that the term “liberal,” which designates the soft Left in North America, designates its opposite in France or Latin America. By this standard, not only neoliberalism but “liberalism” also doesn’t really exist.
    Quote Originally Posted by Crissi View Post
    i think I have my posse filled out now. Mars is Theo, Jupiter is Vanyali, Linadra is Venus, and Heather is Mercury. Dragon can be Pluto.
    On MMO-C we learn that Anti-Fascism is locking arms with corporations, the State Department and agreeing with the CIA, But opposing the CIA and corporate America, and thinking Jews have a right to buy land and can expect tenants to pay rent THAT is ultra-Fash Nazism. Bellingcat is an MI6/CIA cut out. Clyburn Truther.

  19. #19
    I'm surprised anyone read that text-wall, let alone responded.

  20. #20
    Pandaren Monk wunksta's Avatar
    10+ Year Old Account
    Join Date
    Mar 2012
    Location
    Austin, TX
    Posts
    1,953
    Quote Originally Posted by Theodarzna View Post
    Neoliberalism sets itself apart in a sense because it aims to reeducate the masses—housebreak them so to speak, into accepting the penetration of the market into every aspect of their lives. "The market" doesn't give you what you wanted; you have to capitulate to what "the market" wants.
    Yeah, we've seen that with the Monroe Doctrine and the Red Scare. It's been beaten into our heads by corporate shills that anything remotely resembling socialism is a threat to American way of life. People have looked the other way for decades while other countries were 'taught' the right way to run their markets. It's why Iran is the way it is now, due to Operation Ajax. The books War is a Racket, Globalization and Its Discontents, Hegemony or Survival and Killing Hope were pretty insightful growing up. There's a stark contrast of what our government does and how the media sells it.

Posting Permissions

  • You may not post new threads
  • You may not post replies
  • You may not post attachments
  • You may not edit your posts
  •